Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Clout, activists and budget: The road to presidency

  • Lucas Böttcher ,

    Roles Conceptualization, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Software, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    lucasb@ethz.ch

    Affiliation ETH Zurich, Wolfgang-Pauli-Strasse 27, CH-8093 Zurich, Switzerland

  • Hans J. Herrmann,

    Roles Conceptualization, Funding acquisition, Investigation, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – review & editing

    Affiliations ETH Zurich, Wolfgang-Pauli-Strasse 27, CH-8093 Zurich, Switzerland, Universidade Federal do Ceará, Departamento de Füsica, Fortaleza, Brazil

  • Hans Gersbach

    Roles Conceptualization, Formal analysis, Investigation, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    Affiliation ETH Zurich, Zürichbergstrasse 18, CH-8092 Zurich, Switzerland

Abstract

Political campaigns involve, in the simplest case, two competing campaign groups which try to obtain a majority of votes. We propose a novel mathematical framework to study political campaign dynamics on social networks whose constituents are either political activists or persuadable individuals. Activists are convinced and do not change their opinion and they are able to move around in the social network to motivate persuadable individuals to vote according to their opinion. We describe the influence of the complex interplay between the number of activists, political clout, budgets, and campaign costs on the campaign result. We also identify situations where the choice of one campaign group to send a certain number of activists already pre-determines their victory. Moreover, we show that a candidate’s advantage in terms of political clout can overcome a substantial budget disadvantage or a lower number of activists, as illustrated by the US presidential election 2016.

Introduction

Due to the advancement of network science, it has become possible to incorporate the salient features of opinion formation and spreading into large-scale network models [17]. The study of political mobilization is one example of such opinion dynamics, which allowed remarkable observations such as the identification of universal features in elections [8], the importance of easily persuadable individuals for opinion cascades [9], the impact of online social influence [10] and the necessity of social reinforcement in order to convince people [1113].

In recent years, political mobilization and the associated campaigns became more and more sophisticated due to online social media, the availability of data on personal preferences and the huge financial campaign support [1416]. Still, the influence of campaign characteristics such as the number of political activists, political clout or the size of the campaign budget on actual outcomes is not well understood. A more profound understanding of political campaigns is necessary to appropriately interpret the corresponding outcomes and to possibly redesign certain aspects of campaign policies [17]. Thus, we propose a novel mathematical framework to describe political campaign dynamics on networks. More specifically, we account for the fact that mobile political activists can convince persuadable individuals under certain efficiency and cost restrictions. We demonstrate the existence of one unique stationary solution and rigorously describe the interplay between activists, political clout, budgets and campaign costs on this state, thereby understanding how candidates can win elections. We find that a given budget might allow different choices of the number of activists, such that campaign groups find themselves in an activist-choice game. In these strategic situations, a campaign group chooses activists as a best response to the choice of the other campaign group, which may be crucial for winning the election. Interestingly, some activist combinations lead to strong competition and thus to a large campaign budget. Furthermore, an advantage in terms of political clout can overcome a substantial budget disadvantage or a lower number of activists. This is illustrated for the US presidential election of 2016, in which the winner had a huge budget disadvantage and a lower number of activists to support him.

Election campaigns are an essential component of democratic politics. They have been studied extensively by scholars across social sciences and political sciences, in particular, as surveyed recently in Ref. [18]. Three characteristics from this rich body of literature are particularly important for the construction of our model and its investigation:

  1. Some voters are amenable to persuasion and opinion switching, i.e., they might be induced to vote for either candidate if approached by a corresponding campaign activist. In the US presidential election of 2016, the proportion of undecided voters was estimated to be around 20% to 25% [19]. The share of persuadable voters is also large for elections below presidential level,
  2. The most effective tactics in campaigns are personal interactions between activists and persuadable voters, such as door-to-door interaction or phone calls [20],
  3. Money matters in campaigns. The benefit of campaign expenditures is positive, but typically low and subject to rapid decay [20].

Materials and methods

We consider a network with N nodes. Each node is either occupied by an individual having an opinion A or B or it is in an unoccupied state O. The total number of nodes is thus N = NA + NB + NO. Both campaign groups consist of political activists A+ and B+ and persuadable individuals A0 and B0, such that NA = NA+ + NA0 and NB = NB+ + NB0. We illustrate the campaign model in Fig 1. Activists have a fixed opinion and they are able to move from their current location to unoccupied nodes to convince persuadable individuals who do not change their location. Each campaign group is given a finite budget and respectively, and a certain cost cA and cB, respectively, has to be paid for every attempt at convincing a group of persuadable individuals. More specifically, an activist A+ has the possibility to occupy an empty node O from any place in order to change with probability ρA ∈ (0, 1] the opinion of neighboring B0 nodes. The activist A+ only moves and convinces other B0 nodes if the utility condition ρA#B0cA > 0 is fulfilled and if enough budget is available. Here #B0 represents the number of neighboring nodes of the empty node which are in state B0. If the A+ activist does move onto the empty node, independent of the number of persuaded B0 nodes, the cost cA is deducted from the budget [21]. The same applies to activists B+, however, with probability ρB, cost cB and budget .

thumbnail
Fig 1. Illustration of the campaign model.

An illustration of the campaign model where nodes and their corresponding edges are represented by colored circles and black lines respectively. In this example, an A+ activist node is going to occupy an empty node O to convince B0 nodes. The utility condition ρA#B0cA > 0 in this case is, for example, fulfilled for ρA = 1 and cA = 2.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0193199.g001

From now on, we consider the fractions a = A/N, b = B/N and o = O/N of the states A, B and O respectively. The initial values are given by a0(0), b0(0), a+(0), b+(0) and o(0). By definition of our model, we know that only a0 and b0 change over time. Thus, , , and thus a+(t) = a+(0), b+(t) = b+(0) and o(t) = o(0). It is now possible to derive mean-field rate equations of and by assuming a perfectly mixed population in the thermodynamic limit. Mean-field approximations have been proven useful to gain important insights about a given spreading dynamics [22, 23], and many real-world social networks are well described by mean-field approximations [24]. Our analytical results are supported by stochastic kinetic Monte Carlo simulations [25, 26]. For analytical tractability, we assume a regular network with fixed degree k, i.e. a fixed number of neighbors. A mean-field approach for general degree distributions fk is presented in Refs. [27, 28] and is based on an additional weighted sum accounting for different degrees in the network. We only focus on the derivation of , since b0 = 1 − a+b+oa0. Our first observation is that the utility condition ρA#B0cA > 0 corresponds to a threshold [11, 12, 2732] in the sense that A+ activists only move to empty nodes whose neighborhoods contain at least persuadable nodes in state B0. Here ⌈ ⋅ ⌉ denotes the ceil function since the quantity might not have an integer value. We define the transition functions fA0B0(t) and fB0A0(t) describing transitions A0B0 and B0A0, respectively, and find for our dynamics (1) where Θ(⋅) denotes the Heaviside step function accounting for the fact that opinion changes only occur when enough budget is available and is the multinomial coefficient, such that j + l + m + n + r = k and Skj = {l, m, n, r ≥ 0, l + m + n + r = kj}. The prefactor o in Eq (1) accounts for the necessity for a node to be empty before an activist can occupy it, and ρA, ρB denote the probabilities to persuade others, henceforth convincing probabilities. The first double sum describes transitions B0A0 where at least nodes of type B0 need to be available according to the utility condition. The second term describes reverse transitions A0B0. We notice that no change occurs if and . The cost deductions from the respective budgets are described by (2) (3) with the initial conditions , where and are the campaign budgets of the two campaign groups, respectively. In general, our model could also be extended to more than two campaign groups, i.e. more than two candidates. It is then necessary to account for the additional corresponding costs, convincing probabilities and transition functions.

In the Supporting Information, we demonstrate that the dynamics captured by Eq (1) exhibits a unique stationary solution for a given set of initial conditions. Furthermore, we show that there is a complex interplay between the fractions of activists, convincing probabilities and costs. In the case of ρA = ρB and cA = cB, the campaign group with the larger fraction of activists obtains the majority. Otherwise, different convincing probabilities and different costs lead to a shift of the stationary states. In particular, a large convincing probability and small cost is advantageous for the respective campaign group. Convincing probabilities cannot be interchanged with the fractions of activists. Small convincing probabilities and large costs lead to longer transients and to stationary states that are closer together, i.e., small gaps between the final campaign results. Unlike the activist fractions, convincing probabilities and costs also enter in the threshold condition. We also discuss one example in the Supporting Information, which illustrates how the influence of ρ and c might, surprisingly, lead to a change in the majority structure.

Results

Budget limitations

A political campaign typically lasts a fixed time T. We assume that political campaigns have information about the convincing probabilities ρA and ρB as well as the costs cA and cB. A typical goal of each campaign is to convince as many people as possible by spending the available budget in such a way that there is no money left at time T when campaigns start at time 0. Intuitively, the amount of budget spent does not only depend on the costs and the convincing probabilities but also on the number of activists in each campaign group. In particular, the budget will be exhausted faster than budget if the initial budgets, the costs and the convincing probabilities are equal but the fraction of activists of campaign group B is larger than the one of group A. This might be problematic if the campaign lasts longer than the time until budget exhaustion, since campaign group B will lose its majority sooner or later. We illustrate this effect in Fig 2 (left) where numerical simulations are presented together with the corresponding mean-field approximation. The finite size and the finite degree of the underlying random regular network lead to deviations from the mean-field perfect mixing assumption. For large degrees one finds better agreement between simulations and mean-field results [27]. Still, the simulated dynamics is qualitatively captured by Eq (1). To better understand the influence of budget restrictions, we now focus on two relevant points related to the latter example: (i) we want to determine the minimum necessary budget for given fractions of activists a+, b+ and a given campaign duration, and (ii) we want to discuss strategies when to send how many activists to effectively use a given budget so that it lasts until the campaign ends.

thumbnail
Fig 2. Influence of budget restrictions.

The time evolution of the fractions of persuadable nodes a0(t), b0(t), activists a+(t), b+(t), empty nodes o(t) as well as the budgets and . The shown curves are the results of a stochastic simulation on a random regular network with N = 105 nodes, k = 10 and the following initial conditions: a0(0) = 0.54, b0(0) = 0.01, a+(0) = 0.1, b+(0) = 0.15 and o(0) = 0.2. The convincing probabilities are fixed to ρA = ρB = 1 and the costs to cA = cB = 2. The thick grey curves are the numerical mean-field solutions of Eq (2). In the left panel, the budgets are exhausted after some time due to the small initial values and , and thus the evolution changes. On the other hand, in the right panel, the initial budgets and are chosen to be large enough not to influence the evolution during the given time horizon.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0193199.g002

We begin with the discussion of point (i) and find that the minimum necessary budgets are (4) (5) according to Eqs (2) and (3). To solve the integrals defined by Eqs (4) and (5), one first has to solve Eq (1), assuming sufficient resources, i.e. and for all times. This solution has then to be used to compute the integrals, which yields unique solutions. We again look at Fig 2 (left), where the initial budget turns out to be insufficient for a duration T = 15. What is the necessary minimum in this case? We solve Eqs (4) and (5) and find that the mean-field initial budgets are and . We clearly see in Fig 2 (right) that these budgets are sufficient. Due to the perfect mixing assumption, the mean-field dynamics tends to be slightly faster than the one of the simulations.

Strategic choices of activists

For the discussion of point (ii), it is important to realize that while Eqs (4) and (5) yield unique minimal budgets for given a+, b+ and T, finding the two fractions of activists, for given campaign budgets and a duration T, is not a unique operation.

Here we solely focus on choosing constant fractions of activists a+, b+ within the interval (0, 0.3], since a+ and b+ are typically not too large. Fig 3 (left) helps to gain some intuition for the existence of multiple possible choices of a+ and b+ for given campaign budgets. We assumed equal convincing probabilities and costs. In this case, the campaign group with the larger fraction of activists wins the campaign in the limit of long times, as shown in the Supporting Information. Fig 3 (left) shows the solutions of Eqs (4) and (5) for a+ ∈ (0, 0.3] and three values of b+ ∈ {0.04, 0.2, 0.3}. All solutions are parabolas with a characteristic maximum originating from the competition between the two campaign groups. If one or the other campaign dominates, a relatively small budget suffices due to the small average number of opinion changes per unit of time, i.e. small transition functions in Eqs (2) and (3). However, if the two activist fractions are of similar size, the resulting competition leads to a larger necessary budget due to the larger transition functions in Eqs (2) and (3). Considering a limited small budget, it is thus unfavorable for campaign groups to have activist numbers facilitating strong competition. Consequently, choosing the right number of activists is crucial for winning the election. In the more general case, one has to take the other parameters ρA, ρB, cA and cB into account which can lead to shifted maxima.

thumbnail
Fig 3. Minimal budgets for different activist fractions.

We set k = 10 and used the following initial conditions: a0(0) = b0(0) = (1 − a+b+o)/2 with o(0) = 0.2. The convincing probabilities are fixed to ρA = ρB = 1 and the costs to cA = cB = 2. In the left panel, the minimal budgets and according to Eqs (4) and (5) are displayed as a function of the fraction a+ for different values of b+. The black solid line indicates a given budget for campaign of duration T = 15 and the orange areas represent the corresponding regimes of possible choices for a+ for which the given budget suffices. The right panel shows a three-dimensional illustration of the budget as a function of a+ and b+. The plane again represents a given budget . All values of a+ and b+ leading to budget values below or on the plane are possible choices to have a sufficient budget.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0193199.g003

We now want to graphically determine a tuple (a+, b+) such that a budget given to each campaign group suffices throughout the campaign duration. We assume a budget for campaign of duration T = 15 and observe that, for example, in the case of b+ = 0.04 it would allow for two solution branches, indicated by the orange areas in Fig 3 (left), where a+ > 0.27 or a+ < 0.05. In general, a given small budget restricts the possible choices of a+ and b+ to values on or below a plane, as shown in Fig 3 (right). If exceeds the maximum of the parabolas, all constellations of a+ and b+ are possible for the budgets to be sufficient, i.e. a+, b+ ∈ (0, 1). Interestingly, in the case of a small budget leading to two solution branches as in Fig 3 (left), one can interpret the situation as follows. Campaign group B, for example, takes a value of b+ = 0.3. Then group A can either send a very small fraction or one close or equal to b+. In this case, group B would never lose, but depending on the choice of group A, the difference between the final numbers of individuals in each campaign group would be smaller for larger a+. However, if group B takes a smaller value such as b+ = 0.04, campaign group A has the possibility to send a larger fraction to win the campaign. Therefore, the decision for a certain activist fraction made by one campaign group affects the possible choices of the other group. The right initial choice is important for winning the election.

Next we look at the Nash equilibria of the strategic choices in the ensuing activist game as illustrated in Fig 3 (left). Formally, we investigate the best responses of the game defined by (6) A Nash equilibrium is a constellation (a+, b+) that solves both problems. In our example a larger fraction of activists increases the chance of winning and we obtain three best responses for a fixed b+ ∈ {0.04, 0.2, 0.3} As a consequence of the parameters and initial conditions used in Fig 3, the tuples obey the following symmetry: (x, y)b+ given = (y, x)a+ given. The game admits multiple equilibria. Besides (0.3, 0.3), for instance, there also exists another symmetric equilibrium around (0.044, 0.044). Moreover, two campaigns with identical parameters, clout and budget are compatible with a constellation in which A wins with a majority. The opposite constellation also exists, however. In practice, when the activists are not chosen simultaneously, we can look at how a campaign group can generate a first-mover advantage by choosing a large but still affordable number of activists that forces the other group to choose a lower number of activists. The preceding observation suggests that in a race of two campaigns having identical parameters and budgets, the campaign wins that first has assembled the right number of activists.

Can clout compensate a lower budget and fewer activists?

The model outlined above can be used to study political campaigns for specific parameter environments and to address campaign regulation. As an example we illustrate an application of the model and illustrate a phenomenon observed in the recent presidential election in the US battleground states. Three characteristics are widely discussed. First, Donald Trump had a significantly lower budget than Hillary Clinton [14]. More precisely, he had half of Clinton’s budget (404 versus 807 million US dollars). Second, Clinton had a higher number of volunteers than Trump (7% versus 4%) [33]. Third, Trump was able to flip millions of white Obama supporters to his side. We thus investigate whether an advantage in terms of clout could compensate both a significantly lower budget and a lower share of activists. The clout is quantified through the convincing probabilities ρA and ρB. In Fig 4 we illustrate a campaign situation roughly comparable to the one of the US presidential election 2016. We interpret campaign group A as the Clinton group, whereas group B represents Trump’s campaign. We set the initial values of persuadable individuals to a0(0) = 0.32 and b0(0) = 0.205, taking into account the initial majority structure of the actual US presidential election 2016 poll data [34]. Considering the aforementioned presidential election characteristics, we set a+ = 0.175, b+ = 0.1, , to account for the different budgets and numbers of activists ( and a+/b+ = 7/4). Furthermore, we assume equal costs cA = cB = 0.3 and first study the case of equal convincing probabilities ρA = ρB = 0.1, as illustrated in Fig 4 (left). As demonstrated in the Supporting Information, only the relative fraction λ = a+/b+ matters in determining the winning campaign if the convincing probabilities and costs are equal—campaign group A wins if λ > 1. This is the reason for our choice of a+/b+ = 0.175/0.1 = 7/4. Clearly, the Clinton campaign group A dominates the dynamics due to the larger fraction of activists. However, in Fig 4 (right), we show that additional clout can compensate a significantly lower number of activists and a lower budget. Of course, one cannot say that Donald J. Trump won the US presidential elections only because of more political clout. Other factors such as targeted campaigns or the sophisticated use of social media have also been important for his success [35, 36]. The example discussed here just illustrates the strong influence of political clout on the campaign outcome.

thumbnail
Fig 4. Clout versus budget and activists.

The time evolution of the fractions of persuadable voters a0(t), b0(t), activists a+(t), b+(t), empty nodes o(t) as well as the budgets and . The shown curves are the results of a stochastic simulation on a random regular network with N = 105 nodes, k = 10 and the following initial conditions: a0(0) = 0.32, b0(0) = 0.205, a+(0) = 0.175, b+(0) = 0.1 and o(0) = 0.2. The cost is set to cA = cB = 0.3. The grey curves are the numerical mean-field solutions of Eq (2). The left panel shows the situation where both campaign groups have activists with ρA = ρB = 0.1. In the right panel, the convincing probability in campaign group B has been increased to a value of ρB = 0.18, leading to a change of the majority structure.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0193199.g004

This observation has broader implications for the resilience of democracy, as it is related to recent phenomena associated with populism. Candidates who promise to protect citizens from unemployment or income shocks caused by disruptions due to globalization or automation may be able to generate sufficient clout [37]. Such candidates may win election campaigns even if they will not be able to keep their promises or even enact detrimental policies.

Finally, we compare the simulation results presented in Fig 4 (left) with the US presidential election polls 2016, bearing in mind that the poll data did not reproduce the final result, as illustrated in Fig 5. For this comparison we rescaled the simulation results to match the initial values of the polls and the corresponding poll duration. As outlined above, our simulations take into account the empirically determined fractions of activists and assume values of ρA = ρB = 0.1 and cA = cB = 0.3. It has not been possible to determine these values empirically. Since convincing probabilities and costs are equal in this example, Clinton’s campaign group wins due to the larger number of activists. We find that the simulated poll trajectories qualitatively correspond to the actual poll data. Assuming other values of convincing probabilities and costs would imply a different characteristic convergence time scale and a different gap between the final campaign results as shown in the Supporting Information. One would, however, still observe a qualitatively similar convergence behavior.

thumbnail
Fig 5. Poll and simulation results of the US presidential election 2016.

Blue and red curves represent the poll results for Hillary Clinton and Donald Trump, respectively. We compare the poll results with our simulation (grey line) using a random regular network with N = 105 nodes, k = 10 and the following initial conditions: a0(0) = 0.32, b0(0) = 0.205, a+(0) = 0.175, b+(0) = 0.1 and o(0) = 0.2. The cost is set to cA = cB = 0.3 and the convincing probabilities to ρA = ρB = 0.1. The results of the simulations have been rescaled to match the initial values of the polls and the corresponding duration. The data has been taken from http://elections.huffingtonpost.com/pollster/2016-general-election-trump-vs-clinton.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0193199.g005

Discussion

We have developed a novel framework to study political campaign dynamics on social networks based on three essential features: moving activists, political clout and campaign budgets. We illustrated how the complex interplay between these factors determines the success of a campaign group. Our results imply that the right initial choice of the number of activists might lead to an important advantage in winning a campaign. In addition, we also showed that typical campaign characteristics can be taken into account by our model allowing to apply it to the US presidential election of 2016. What is more, our model opens up many further applications. For instance, we could introduce caps on campaign budgets to study how such regulations impact the outcome of elections. Furthermore, our framework allows to integrate additional channels such as media or targeting [38] which strongly influence campaigns. Finally, by introducing preferences of citizens about policy-making once a candidate is in office, we can identify conditions under which a politician may win and enacts policies that will harm a majority of citizens.

Supporting information

S1 File. Supporting information.

Additional information and mathematical proofs.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0193199.s001

(PDF)

Acknowledgments

We acknowledge financial support from the ETH Risk Center and ERC Advanced grant number FP7-319968 FlowCCS of the European Research Council. We thank Moritz Hoferer for his input regarding the strategic choices of activists and for proofreading the manuscript. L.B. wants to thank Sergio Solórzano for interesting discussions.

References

  1. 1. Sznajd-Weron K, Sznajd J. Opinion evolution in closed community. Int J Mod Phys C. 2000;11(6):1157–1165.
  2. 2. Deffuant G, Neau D, Amblard F, Weisbuch G. Mixing beliefs among interacting agents. Adv Complex Syst. 2000;3:87–98.
  3. 3. Hegselmann R, Krause U. Opinion dynamics and bounded confidence models, analysis, and simulation. J Artif Soc Soc Simulat. 2002;5(3).
  4. 4. Krapivsky PL, Redner S. Dynamics of Majority Rule in Two-State Interacting Spin Systems. Phys Rev Lett. 2003;90(23):238701. pmid:12857298
  5. 5. Schwämmle V, González MC, Moreira AA, Andrade JS Jr, Herrmann HJ. Different topologies for a herding model of opinion. Phys Rev E. 2007;75:066108.
  6. 6. Shao J, Havlin S, Stanley HE. Dynamic Opinion Model and Invasion Percolation. Phys Rev Lett. 2009;103:018701. pmid:19659181
  7. 7. Ramos M, Shao J, Reis SDS, Anteneodo C, Andrade JS Jr, Havlin S, et al. How does public opinion become extreme? Sci Rep. 2015;5:10032. pmid:25989484
  8. 8. Fortunato S, Castellano C. Scaling and universality in proportional elections. Phys Rev Lett. 2007;99:138701. pmid:17930647
  9. 9. Watts DJ, Peter Dodds S. Influentials, Networks, and Public Opinion Formation. J Consum Res. 2007;34(4):441–458.
  10. 10. Bond RM, Fariss CJ, Jones JJ, Kramer ADI, Marlow C, Settle JE, et al. A 61-million-person experiment in social influence and political mobilization. Nature. 2012;489:295–298. pmid:22972300
  11. 11. Chwe MS. Structure and Strategy in Collective Action. Am J Sociol. 1999;105(1):128–156.
  12. 12. Granovetter M. Threshold models of collective behavior. Am J Sociol. 1978;83(6):1420–1443.
  13. 13. Rogers EM. Diffusion of Innovations. Simon and Schuster; 2010.
  14. 14. Insidegov.com, Compare Presidential Candidates 2016, retrieved August 31, 2017. http://presidential-candidates.insidegov.com/;.
  15. 15. Ramswell PQ. derision, division–decision: parallels between Brexit and the 2016 US presidential election. Eur Polit Sci. 2017;16(2):217–232.
  16. 16. Böttcher L, Woolley-Meza O, Brockmann D. Temporal dynamics of online petitions. PLoS ONE. 2017;12:e0178062. pmid:28542492
  17. 17. Gersbach H. Redesigning Democracy: More Ideas for Better Rules. Springer; 2017.
  18. 18. Jacobson GC. How do campaigns matter? Annu Rev Polit Sci. 2015;18:31–47.
  19. 19. Kenski K, Hardy BW, Jamieson KH. The Obama victory: How media, money, and message shaped the 2008 election. 2010;.
  20. 20. Jacobson GC, Carson JL. The politics of congressional elections. 2015;.
  21. 21. Böttcher L, Woolley-Meza O, Araújo NAM, Herrmann HJ, Helbing D. Disease-induced resource constraints can trigger explosive epidemics. Sci Rep. 2015;5:16571. pmid:26568377
  22. 22. Keeling MJ, Rohani P. Modeling Infectious Diseases in Humans and Animals. Princeton University Press; 2008.
  23. 23. Marro J, Dickman R. Nonequilibrium Phase Transitions in Lattice Models. Cambridge University Press; 2005.
  24. 24. Gleeson JP, Melnik S, Ward JA, Porter MA, Mucha PJ. Accuracy of mean-field theory for dynamics on real-world networks. Phys Rev E. 2012;85:026106.
  25. 25. Gillespie DT. A General Method for Numerically Simulating the Stochastic Time Evolution of Coupled Chemical Reactions. J Comput Phys. 1976;22(4):403–434.
  26. 26. Gillespie DT. Exact Stochastic Simulation of Coupled Chemical Reactions. J Phys Chem. 1977;81(25):2340–2361.
  27. 27. Böttcher L, Luković M, Nagler J, Havlin S, Herrmann HJ. Failure and recovery in embedded networks. Sci Rep. 2017;7:41729. pmid:28155876
  28. 28. Böttcher L, Nagler J, Herrmann HJ. Critical Behaviors in Contagion Dynamics. Phys Rev Lett. 2017;118:088301. pmid:28282207
  29. 29. Watts DJ. A simple model of global cascades on random networks. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2002;99:5766–5771. pmid:16578874
  30. 30. Centola D, Macy M. Complex contagions and the weakness of long ties. Am J Sociol. 2007;113(3):702–734.
  31. 31. Easley D, Kleinberg J. Networks, crowds, and markets: Reasoning about a highly connected world. Cambridge University Press; 2010.
  32. 32. Gleeson JP. Binary-State Dynamics on Complex Networks: Pair Approximation and Beyond. Phys Rev X. 2013;3:021004.
  33. 33. Ariel Edwards-Levy, Volunteering For A Campaign Or Going To Rallies? You’re In The Minority, Huffpost, 11.01.2016, retrieved August 31, 2017. https://www.huffingtonpost.com/entry/campaign-volunteering-rallies-poll_us_581906b8e4b0f96eba968ca7;.
  34. 34. Poll Chart 2016 General Election: Trump vs. Clinton, Huffpost Pollster, retrieved August 31, 2017. http://elections.huffingtonpost.com/pollster/2016-general-election-trump-vs-clinton;.
  35. 35. Francia PL. Free media and Twitter in the 2016 US presidential election: The unconventional campaign of Donald Trump. Soc Sci Comput Rev. 2017;.
  36. 36. Cambridge Analytica Platform. Donald J. Trump for President: A Full-Scale Data-Driven Digital Campaign; 2016.
  37. 37. Rodrik D. Populism and the Economics of Globalization. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No 23559. 2017;.
  38. 38. Böttcher L, Andrade JS Jr, Herrmann HJ. Targeted Recovery as an Effective Strategy against Epidemic Spreading. Sci Rep. 2017;7:14356. pmid:29085046